By Evan Abrams
The global financial crisis of 2007-08 may have begun in the
private sector, but it quickly spread to the public sector as well, with
countries like Greece, Portugal, and Italy making headlines for months. The
crisis exposed these countries’ inability to finance their debt and left the
specter of a Eurozone breakup battering financial markets across the world.
Argentina has also made news
of late due to its long running legal battle with so called “vulture funds.”
The situation with Argentina is not that they are unable to pay their debts,
but that they are unwilling to reward holdouts from an earlier restructuring
after its 2001 default. These holdouts claim they are simply trying to recover
what they are contractually owed. However, developing countries view such
recalcitrant creditors as taking advantage of economic crises and undermining nations’
recovery efforts in the wake of financial turmoil.
Both the Argentine court battles and European restructurings
have prompted renewed
calls for a better system to deal with sovereign debt crises. Such calls
have come from a group of 130
developing countries at the UN, leading economists including Joseph
Stiglitz, and prominent IMF
officials. The proposed debt restructuring system is typically referred to
as a sovereign debt restricting mechanism or SDRM. The SDRM was first floated
in 2003, in response to the East Asian financial crisis and has been
periodically revived since then. According to the Economist,
“the IMF would evaluate a state’s capacity to pay, institute a reform
programme and determine a haircut for creditors.” This would prevent the
lengthy and somewhat ad-hoc process that currently exists, which typically
entails prolonged negotiations between creditors and debtors and often devolves
into years-long litigation in New York or London. This creates uncertainty and
means economic recovery could easily be delayed or frustrated. The SDRM should
in theory fast track this process while making it more transparent and predictable.
However, not everyone is a fan of the SDRM.
Developed countries and private sector financiers are particularly weary of it.
They argue
that the SDRM would give additional leverage to the debtor states that already
hold outsized bargaining power. Because any restructuring mechanism would
likely lack real enforcement power, a country could pursue restructuring under
the SDRM and then decide to default anyways if it did not like the terms the
SDRM set out. Since lenders would have to surrender their right to litigate
when purchasing debt issued under the SDRM model, creditors would have very
limited means to try to force compliance.
Detractors also contend
that the SDRM would harm debtors. They see the systems implementation littered
with practical problems, including the lack of an independent body to run the
mechanism (since the IMF is itself a lender and thus an interested party). They
further contend that the SDRM might inadvertently raise borrowing costs by
making the prospect of a default somewhat more palatable for borrowers and
diminishing trust in the markets by placing bureaucrats and institutions between
creditors and debtors. A rise in borrowing costs would ultimately hurt the very
countries advocating for the SDRM.
Finally, it is argued that the need for
the SDRM has largely been eclipsed by the introduction of collective
action clauses, which allow a supermajority of bond
holders to bind all holders to an agreed upon restructuring. These clauses were
introduced following Argentina’s first default in 2001 and have gained further
traction since the global financial crisis of 2008. Their introduction has been
viewed as a success by many observers; however, they are not included in all
new debt issuances. The clauses also apply to specific bond issues rather than
all outstanding debt that includes a clause. This means a majority of just one
issue could create
havoc on an entire restructuring. Further, merely reaching the required
supermajority to trigger the clause could be a challenge in many situations.
Where does all of this leave us? There
are clearly legitimate arguments for and against an SDRM. A clear answer will
likely remain elusive, but if the recent global financial crisis taught us
anything, it is the potential for a disorderly default to have devastating
financial consequences across the world and across all sectors of the economy.
The creation of the SDRM would certainly present many challenges (a binding
enforcement mechanism being foremost), but if the SDRM can provide additional
transparency and predictability for the world’s financial markets it must be
seriously considered.
0 comments:
Post a Comment